We haven't been able to take payment
You must update your payment details via My Account or by clicking update payment details to keep your subscription.
Act now to keep your subscription
We've tried to contact you several times as we haven't been able to take payment. You must update your payment details via My Account or by clicking update payment details to keep your subscription.
Your subscription is due to terminate
We've tried to contact you several times as we haven't been able to take payment. You must update your payment details via My Account, otherwise your subscription will terminate.
JESSE NORMAN

A history of free trade — and the deep irony of ‘liberation day’

To understand the folly of this chaotic week, look to the 1770s, when the economist Adam Smith showed the path to prosperity and the US blazed the trail

Illustration of exploding cardboard boxes with various country flags.
ILLUSTRATION BY TONY BELL
The Sunday Times

When President Trump called his introduction of sweeping global tariffs “liberation day”, the echoes of the US Declaration of Independence in 1776 were surely deliberate.

President Trump holding a chart of reciprocal tariffs at a White House event.
President Trump’s tariffs, which he announced on Wednesday, have made waves across the global economy
CHIP SOMODEVILLA/GETTY IMAGES

But more significant still for the present debate about tariffs is the other great event of that remarkable year: the publication of the Scottish economist Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations. For it is that book more than any other that provides the key to understanding what is really going on here.

Smith is on any objective measure by far the most influential economist who ever lived, often described as the father of economics. He is celebrated for his advocacy of open markets, and for his analysis of how the basic human instinct to “truck, barter and exchange” creates economic value.

Portrait painting of Adam Smith.
Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations was published in 1776
ALAMY

If I have saucepans and you have oranges, then we can both benefit from freely exchanging some of what we have with each other. Multiply those exchanges across a nation, and the result is a miracle of benign unintended consequences. A massive, co-ordinated economy emerges, with no central planner or directing organisation, working as though by an “invisible hand”, simply created by people freely buying and selling.

What matters for Smith is not the rhetoric of free markets, but the reality of effective competition. It is competition that creates shared economic value and keeps markets honest. Let a monopoly or cartel flourish, however, or impose a foolish tax, and that shared value can rapidly erode.

Advertisement

Yet Smith was far from naive: he recognised that while the actions of government could easily damage markets, it was government enforcement of the rule of law and of private contracts that allowed markets to function at all.

What the Trump slump means for your money

The same lesson about competition broadly holds, Smith believed, between one nation and another; both sides will usually benefit from the free exchange of goods and services. Indeed, as Smith’s great successor David Ricardo showed in his theory of comparative advantage, both nations can benefit even when one can produce all the relevant goods more cheaply than the other, or is far wealthier than the other.

Portrait of David Ricardo, British economist.
The British economist and MP David Ricardo
HULTON ARCHIVE/GETTY IMAGES

These are among the foundational insights of modern economics. But they have a vital corollary: that distortions of international trade through monopoly, cartel or taxes can quickly destroy wealth and value.

In the 18th century, British domestic markets were ensnarled by thickets of guild, church and local regulation, jealously guarded by insiders with privileged access to government. But Smith also viewed many politicians as being under the sway of a specific economic doctrine, later known as mercantilism, at which he took special aim.

Advertisement

For Smith, the “mercantile system” was marked by its obsession with money, and a simple-minded equation of wealth with money. Just as a merchant seeks to acquire wealth by storing up money, so a mercantilist nation sought to acquire wealth by storing up gold and silver bullion.

How was this bullion to be obtained? In the 18th century, by foreign conquest and the acquisition of mines; but also, and more insidiously, by attempts to manage and manipulate the balance of trade. The mercantilist saw the import of goods not as a vital source of competition, but as a subversive force that undermined domestic manufacturing and stimulated the outflow of money, and so the loss of wealth.

The balance of trade thus lay at the centre of mercantilism. Complex systems of regulation and taxation were developed to promote exports and limit imports, and so also limit the outflow of money. These included duties, prohibitions, bounties, subsidies, reliefs, advantageous commercial treaties and colonies, with their attendant privileges and monopolies. It was of course Britain’s mercantilist Tea Act of 1773, with its duties on tea imports, that so outraged the American colonists and led to the Boston Tea Party.

Illustration of the Boston Tea Party.
The Boston Tea Party protest in 1773
DEAGOSTINI/GETTY IMAGES

Smith argued that mercantilism too had unintended consequences, and that these were potentially ruinous. Tariffs were a form of taxation, which raised the cost of imports to domestic consumers and provided subsidies to domestic manufacturers. Mercantilism thus distorted trade and investment, boosted short-term profits, discouraged competition and raised prices, and thus what we would now call inflation.

Worse, it fed the “monopolising spirit” of manufacturers and merchants, whom it taught to recognise that government action could increase their profits at little or no apparent cost. The result was a further boost to the growth of what would now be called business lobbies and special interests, and further detriment to customers and workers.

Advertisement

Smith’s verdict on such actions is damning: “The proposal of any new law or regulation of commerce which comes from this order ought always to be listened to with great precaution … It comes from an order of men … who have generally an interest to deceive and even to oppress the public.”

At its worst, mercantilism fed off, and was in turn stimulated by, an imperial impulse. Colonisation began as a route to the acquisition of raw materials, notably mines and so bullion. It had even extended to include trade in slaves, which Smith had roundly condemned long before the anti-slavery campaigns of Thomas Clarkson and William Wilberforce were launched.

As he saw it, chartered companies such as the East India Company had extracted exclusive privileges and trading monopolies, and had assumed sovereignty over entire countries by force of war. And war inevitably meant a catastrophic increase in public debt.

Painting of an East India Company grandee riding in an Indian procession.
The East India Company held huge power in the 18th and 19th centuries
ANN RONAN PICTURES/GETTY IMAGES

For Smith, therefore, the mercantile system and its flawed assumptions about trade and prosperity lay at the root of Britain’s imperialist ambitions — so much so as to be a principal cause of the American War of Independence itself.

Again, Smith was not naive about the realities of international trade. He recognised that sometimes tariffs and other temporary retaliations might be called for in order to keep the system honest, even though their continued use would tend to raise domestic prices, reduce competition and increase crony capitalism.

Advertisement

These were the ugly but sometimes necessary short-term expedients of what he called “that insidious and crafty animal, vulgarly called a ‘statesman’ or ‘politician’, whose councils are directed by the momentary fluctuations of affairs”.

Indeed, Smith supported the Navigation Acts, a long series of laws enacted throughout the 17th and 18th centuries, through which Britain used its naval power to exercise strict control over its colonial and other trade, insisting that it was routed through Britain. As he put it simply, “defence is of much more importance than opulence”.

But as to the basic logic and legitimacy of mercantilism, and its disastrous long-term effects, he was unsparing. As he put it: “Nothing … can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance of trade.”

Trump’s assault on free trade will do far more harm than good

Trade was not a zero-sum game in which each nation could gain only by beggaring its neighbour, as the mercantilists imagined. On the contrary, such a view was not merely individually unwise but collectively incoherent.

Advertisement

There could never be a trading system of any kind in which every country ran a positive balance of trade. Indeed, some societies — notably the American colonies — could run a negative balance for decades while flourishing and creating enormous wealth.

A century on, as first the agricultural and industrial revolutions and then the empire raised Britain to unimagined heights of economic, political and military influence, deference to Adam Smith had become all but universal.

But the stern injunctions of The Wealth of Nations against colonisation, empire, war and public debt were conveniently forgotten, and its careful lessons about the need for effective competition were transmuted into a catch-all commitment to free trade, at least within the empire.

And these lessons were forgotten again as the world lurched into catastrophic trade wars in the 1930s, catalysed in part by America’s Smoot-Hawley Tariffs Act of 1930, which greatly increased the devastation of the Great Depression.

President Herbert Hoover signing unemployment and drought relief bills.
President Hoover in 1930, and addressing a crowd on the subject of tariffs in West Virginia, below. He served in the role from 1929-1933
AP
President Herbert Hoover addressing a large crowd from a train platform.
BETTMANN

Today, the underlying tensions between the economics of free trade and the politics of protection remain, now as then. The rise of China since its own free market reforms and its admission into the World Trade Organisation in 2001 has been extraordinary.

That rise has reduced poverty faster, and created more human wealth and wellbeing, than any other economic policy change in history. Yet it in turn has driven renewed American concern about trade deficits, unfair competition and an over-valuation of the dollar. China runs a huge trade surplus with America and the relocation of swathes of America manufacturing has hollowed out and corroded communities across the Midwest — places where Trump has scored a decisive political advantage.

The consequence of Trump’s tariff declaration, unexpected to many people but not to students of Adam Smith, may be the acceleration and consolidation of trading blocs — Chinese, American, European — marking new systems of economic preference.

Traders on the floor of the New York Stock Exchange.
Traders on the floor of the New York Stock Exchange react to the effects of Trump’s tariffs
SPENCER PLATT/GETTY IMAGES
Trader at the New York Stock Exchange reacting to market downturn.
TIMOTHY A. CLARY/AFP/GETTY IMAGES

Thus the deep irony is that today, almost exactly 250 years after The Wealth of Nations and the American founding, the White House is at risk of pursuing economic doctrines close in spirit to those whose damaging effects precipitated the revolutionary war that created the United States of America in the first place.

As Adam Smith set out in 1776, if these measures are temporary, their effects may be containable. The world may even emerge with a renewed understanding of the fragility, and the deep value, of free trade. Let us hope so. But one thing is clear: now, more than ever, we need to return to his wisdom.

Jesse Norman MP is the shadow leader of the House of Commons, and the author of Adam Smith: What he Thought and Why it Matters

PROMOTED CONTENT